Skip to main content
The Actuary: The magazine of the Institute and Faculty of Actuaries - return to the homepage Logo of The Actuary website
  • Search
  • Visit The Actuary Magazine on Facebook
  • Visit The Actuary Magazine on LinkedIn
  • Visit @TheActuaryMag on Twitter
Visit the website of the Institute and Faculty of Actuaries Logo of the Institute and Faculty of Actuaries

Main navigation

  • News
  • Features
    • General Features
    • Interviews
    • Students
    • Opinion
  • Topics
  • Knowledge
    • Business Skills
    • Careers
    • Events
    • Predictions by The Actuary
    • Whitepapers
    • Webinars
    • Podcasts
  • Jobs
  • IFoA
    • CEO Comment
    • IFoA News
    • People & Social News
    • President Comment
  • Archive
Quick links:
  • Home
  • The Actuary Issues
  • September 2021
General Features
Opinion

Coughing up on carbon taxation

Open-access content Thursday 2nd September 2021
Authors
Trevor Williams

Trevor Williams gives an economist’s view of carbon taxation

web_p18_Coughing-up_Carbon-Taxing--Currency-with-chimney-bellowing_CREDIT_Mark-Airs_Ikon_00024955.jpg

Of all the significant challenges facing the world, the one that poses the greatest existential risk to humanity is undoubtedly climate change. It is no longer controversial to say that temperature increases of more than a few degrees above a global average of 1.5°C will be lethal to humans. It is, however, not sufficient for us to focus solely on reducing future carbon emissions: action must also be taken now to deal with the heating that has already occurred.

Global warming has become such a major issue now because insufficient steps were taken in previous decades to prevent the outcomes we are currently observing. Reconstructing energy supply and production to achieve not just net-zero carbon emissions but also a fall in absolute emissions will mean significant changes in the coming decades.

What does economics tell us about how this should be done? The answer is, rather a lot.

Polluter pays

First, the polluters must be taxed. We know who they are, and we have known that we must tax them since the 1970s, when David Wilson, a professor of mechanical engineering at the Massachusetts Institute of Technology, devised such a market-based mechanism. The release of carbon gases is what we call a negative externality – it affects the environment and everyone in it, but those creating it have no incentive to stop because it is not part of their internal costs. To make it a part of their cost structure, a regime of taxing the polluters needs to be put in place by regulators with government authority.

Analysis of how to achieve this must start with an honest, factually driven discussion about who is responsible for global warming. Moreover, there needs to be recognition that there is great disparity in the relative wealth of nations, so reducing carbon emissions cannot be equally shared between countries.

It is also the case that not every country is equally responsible for the current situation – more than 50% of the cumulative CO2 in the atmosphere is from Europe and the US, for example. A system ought to be put in place so that those who have historically contributed the most to where we are today face a more significant financial burden, while those who are currently high emitters but are not primarily responsible for the increase in global temperatures will carry less of the burden.

In short, some countries – and some of their companies – will be taxed and treated differently, based on the amounts of greenhouse gases they have released to date. This system can be internationally effective, but only if the governments responsible for overseeing those companies have the political will to ensure that any action taken is enforced everywhere. 

Spreading the load

However, there are some subtle and not-so-subtle fairness issues around carbon taxes and their potential effects on people of different income levels, as well as the economics of firms’ production locations. These will have implications for economic growth and the disparity of living standards between countries.

Carbon taxes will mean price rises, and those price rises will hit those who consume more carbon-intensive products the hardest. To that extent, a tax could have a disproportionate impact on the incomes of those who are poorest, if they have comparable carbon footprints to wealthier households. A mitigating strategy here could be for governments to subsidise those who are on lower incomes to move to less carbon-intensive lifestyles. Income tax cuts and/or rebates would be practical ways to implement such a policy. Avoiding fuel poverty for the poorest must be a political priority, or there is a risk of undermining any carbon pricing strategy.

There is also the risk that a high carbon tax in one country could mean that production is simply moved to a country where the tax is lower, thus negating the tax’s intended impact in terms of emissions reduction. Policymakers would need to be mindful of such unintended consequences and find ways to resolve them.

Nevertheless, a differentiated carbon tax also presents opportunities – for instance, countries and firms that develop new, green technologies fastest will pay a lower carbon tax and benefit from selling more low-emission products.

None of this is rocket science or, indeed, new. It is widely understood, but hard to put into action because of the real challenges of asking people to pay more for what they regard as necessities, rather than luxuries – never mind the situation for those who are already feeling left behind.

Not acting, however, is increasingly no longer an option, as signs of the effects of excessive carbon emissions proliferate. Perhaps the only good news is that this may open up political room for action.

Trevor Williams is an independent economist and a professor of economics at St Mary’s University, London

Image Credit | Mark-Airs_Ikon

ACT Sep21_Full LR.jpg
This article appeared in our September 2021 issue of The Actuary.
Click here to view this issue
Filed in:
General Features
Also filed in:
Opinion
Topics:
Investment
Risk & ERM
Environment

You might also like...

Share
  • Twitter
  • Facebook
  • Linked in
  • Mail
  • Print

Latest Jobs

Senior Underwriting Risk Manager

London (Central)
£85K-£95K + Benefits
Reference
124386

Reserving Manager (Contract)

London (Central)
£1200 - £1400 per day
Reference
124385

Life Actuary - Contract - IFRS 17 Financial Impact

England, London / England, Bristol / North Yorkshire, England
£900 - £1150 per day
Reference
124384
See all jobs »
 
 

Today's top reads

 
 

Sign up to our newsletter

News, jobs and updates

Sign up

Subscribe to The Actuary

Receive the print edition straight to your door

Subscribe
Spread-iPad-slantB-june.png

Topics

  • Data Science
  • Investment
  • Risk & ERM
  • Pensions
  • Environment
  • Soft skills
  • General Insurance
  • Regulation Standards
  • Health care
  • Technology
  • Reinsurance
  • Global
  • Life insurance
​
FOLLOW US
The Actuary on LinkedIn
@TheActuaryMag on Twitter
Facebook: The Actuary Magazine
CONTACT US
The Actuary
Tel: (+44) 020 7880 6200
​

IFoA

About IFoA
Become an actuary
IFoA Events
About membership

Information

Privacy Policy
Terms & Conditions
Cookie Policy
Think Green

Get in touch

Contact us
Advertise with us
Subscribe to The Actuary Magazine
Contribute

The Actuary Jobs

Actuarial job search
Pensions jobs
General insurance jobs
Solvency II jobs

© 2022 The Actuary. The Actuary is published on behalf of the Institute and Faculty of Actuaries by Redactive Publishing Limited. All rights reserved. Reproduction of any part is not allowed without written permission.

Redactive Media Group Ltd, 71-75 Shelton Street, London WC2H 9JQ