Skip to main content
The Actuary: The magazine of the Institute and Faculty of Actuaries - return to the homepage Logo of The Actuary website
  • Search
  • Visit The Actuary Magazine on Facebook
  • Visit The Actuary Magazine on LinkedIn
  • Visit @TheActuaryMag on Twitter
Visit the website of the Institute and Faculty of Actuaries Logo of the Institute and Faculty of Actuaries

Main navigation

  • News
  • Features
    • General Features
    • Interviews
    • Students
    • Opinion
  • Topics
  • Knowledge
    • Business Skills
    • Careers
    • Events
    • Predictions by The Actuary
    • Whitepapers
  • Jobs
  • IFoA
    • CEO Comment
    • IFoA News
    • People & Social News
    • President Comment
  • Archive
Quick links:
  • Home
  • The Actuary Issues
  • July 2014
07

Curved time

Open-access content Thursday 26th June 2014

David Blake and John Pickles examine how our preference for time influences the way we value investments

2

How much will a £1 investment be worth in 30 years' time? And what is that future value worth today? Actuaries are used to pondering such questions, so we're interested in how your clients might answer them. As we'll explain, we suspect that their answer to the second question might not always be £1. It might be more, it might be less. 

In our paper, Value-time curve psychology, we consider a series of 'thought investments' in which the initial value of an investment is projected forward to a future date (prospection) and that future value is discounted back (retrospection) to give a present value. We use 'value-time charts' to trace this mental simulation of changing value over time. 

We show that the first big distinction is between those who value 'exponentially' and those who value 'hyperbolically'. Exponential valuation is standard in time value of money calculations where annual growth rates are assumed to be constant over time. But, in reality, many of us value hyperbolically, anticipating that £1 invested will grow more rapidly in the short-term than in the long-term.

In Chart 1 (below), £1 is projected forward 30 years: exponentially to £5.74 and hyperbolically to £3.32. In this example, the exponential investor is assuming a fixed annual growth rate of 6%. In contrast, the hyperbolic investor initially expects that the investment will grow at a much higher annual rate than 6%. But as the hyperbolic investor looks further into the future, he or she anticipates that the annual return will fall well below 6% and that the average annual return will be just 4%. 

We show the next big distinction is between those who value 'symmetrically', those who value 'myopically' and those who value 'hyperopically'. Traditionally, 'symmetry' has been assumed between prospection and retrospection. An important implication of symmetry is 'temporal neutrality'. In other words, an investor who is temporally neutral has no time preference, that is, no preference for the past, the present or the future. Temporal neutrality, in a thought investment, means the present value always equals the initial value. 

If £1 is compounded forward, at 6% for 30 years, then a symmetric investor will use a 6% discount rate to arrive back at a present value of £1. 

As Chart 2 illustrates, a symmetric investor values at £1 today £1 invested in any asset for any period of time. So, the present value of £1 invested in equities for, say, 35 years with an assumed return of 8% p.a. is the same as £1 invested in bonds for, say, 20 years with an assumed return of 4% p.a., namely £1, even though equities are riskier, offer a higher expected return and are held for a longer period than bonds. In other words, for a symmetric investor £1 worth of equities has the same present value as £1 worth of bonds. 

Recent research in behavioural psychology, however, reveals that the ways in which many of us mentally represent the future and the past differ. Prospection differs, in context and experience, from retrospection. Many of us are not temporally neutral. Some of us are 'myopic' and have 'positive time preference': we value the present more than the future. Some of us, in contrast, are 'hyperopic', we value the future over the present: we have 'negative time preference'. 

Positive time preference, in a thought investment, implies that the present value is less than the initial value. Chart 3 illustrates the myopic investor's value-time curves. 

When valuing exponentially, £1 today is valued at £5.74 in 30 years' time; and £5.74 in 30 years' time at £0.57 today. When valuing hyperbolically, £1 today is projected to grow to £3.32 in 30 years' time and that future value is then discounted to a present value of £0.57. 

By implication, £1 today invested for 30 years is valued at £0.57. In this example, the myopic exponential investor and the myopic hyperbolic investor both happen to give this particular investment the same present value of £0.57, even though the mental time travel journeys each investor took to reach the same present value are very different. In general, we would not expect such different journeys to lead to the same present value. In reality, we would expect the different mental time travel journeys that investors take to lead to a whole range of different present values.

In a thought investment with negative time preference, present value exceeds initial value. Chart 4 shows the hyperopic investor's value-time curves, both when valuing exponentially and hyperbolically. £1 is projected forward exponentially to £5.74 in 30 years' time and then exponentially discounted to a present value of £1.77. And, £1 today is projected hyperbolically to £3.32 and then hyperbolically discounted to £1.77. By implication, £1 today invested for 30 years is valued at £1.77 for these two hyperopic investors, although this need not be the case in general.

We explore, in our paper, the reasons why investors might project and discount non-symmetrically. One reason is their attitude to risk. We explain, for example, why a risk-averse investor might value £1 invested in equities at less than £1 invested in bonds whereas a risk-seeking investor might attribute a higher value to the equities.

Our paper is theoretical, albeit referenced to a comprehensive body of experimental evidence. Our next task is to carry out our own testing. As a first step, we would much appreciate your feedback. In particular, do you recognise, or have any anecdotal evidence of 'symmetric', 'myopic' and 'hyperopic' valuation? Certainly, some traditional actuaries appear to have valued equities hyperopically: they could quite happily switch a pension fund's bonds, valued at £100m, into equities and value the equities at £120m. Presumably this no longer happens?

Curved time graphs

Please download the report at bit.ly/T34juD and then email your comments to [email protected]

This article appeared in our July 2014 issue of The Actuary.
Click here to view this issue
Filed in:
07
Topics:
Investment

You might also like...

Share
  • Twitter
  • Facebook
  • Linked in
  • Mail
  • Print

Latest Jobs

Covenant Consultant

Leeds
£60-80k plus bonus and benefits
Reference
120863

Big 4 Consultancy – Senior Consultant / Manager, Life Actuarial

London / Bristol / Edinburgh
Competitive salary plus bonus
Reference
120771

Capital Optimisation & Balance Sheet Management – Insurance Consolidator

London, Dublin
Competitive salary package + study support if required
Reference
120860
See all jobs »
 
 

Today's top reads

 
 

Sign up to our newsletter

News, jobs and updates

Sign up

Subscribe to The Actuary

Receive the print edition straight to your door

Subscribe
Spread-iPad-slantB-june.png

Topics

  • Data Science
  • Investment
  • Risk & ERM
  • Pensions
  • Environment
  • Soft skills
  • General Insurance
  • Regulation Standards
  • Health care
  • Technology
  • Reinsurance
  • Global
  • Life insurance
​
FOLLOW US
The Actuary on LinkedIn
@TheActuaryMag on Twitter
Facebook: The Actuary Magazine
CONTACT US
The Actuary
Tel: (+44) 020 7880 6200
​

IFoA

About IFoA
Become an actuary
IFoA Events
About membership

Information

Privacy Policy
Terms & Conditions
Cookie Policy
Think Green

Get in touch

Contact us
Advertise with us
Subscribe to The Actuary Magazine
Contribute

The Actuary Jobs

Actuarial job search
Pensions jobs
General insurance jobs
Solvency II jobs

© 2021 The Actuary. The Actuary is published on behalf of the Institute and Faculty of Actuaries by Redactive Publishing Limited, Level 5, 78 Chamber Street, London, E1 8BL. Tel: 020 7880 6200